The setting for Arrow's theorem is a set of rankings. Individuals (voters) order a set of options (candidates) via preferences, and the goal of a ranking scheme (voting system) is to come up with a preference list that respects certain properties:
- universality: the output should be a total order
- non-imposition: every possible order should be achievable
- non-dictatorship: the global preference should not merely follow one of the input rankings
- monotonicity: raising the ranking of a choice cannot hurt it in the overall rankings
- independence of irrelevant alternatives: the "spoiler" condition - rankings of options outside a given subset should not affect the ordering within the subset.
But social choice theory itself has been exploited in a CS context. To understand this, we need another notion, the Condorcet criterion.
One of the criticisms of Arrow's theorem is that the "spoiler" condition is too stringent, and other (weaker) conditions have been proposed that allow for a general voting procedure to exist. The most notable scheme is one that was developed nearly 800 years ago, and was rediscovered by Condorcet in the 18th century (which leads to a topic for another post). The idea is to create a ranking by looking at a series of face-offs. The relative ranking of options A and B is determined by seeing how many voters rank A above B, and taking the majority opinion. This is done for all pairs.
The Condorcet winner is then the option that in a head-to-head matchup beats all other options. Note that a Condorcet winner may not always exist, and this is the problem with using the Condorcet method in its basic form for elections.
The Condorcet criterion is a condition on a ranking scheme.
If any element beats all other elements in head-to-head matchups, it should be ranked first.A generalization of this, the extended Condorcet criterion, states that:
If there is a partition (C, D) of the set S of options such that for each x in C and each y in D, x beats y head-to-head, then x should be ranked above y.So what does all of this have to with computer science ? The application comes from the problem of merging ranked lists. The most common example of this arises when doing meta searches in a number of search engines. If Google ranks pages a certain way and Teoma does it a different way, how should the metasearch engine present results ?
The Condorcet criteria provide a condition that any reasonable ranking scheme must satisfy. The algorithms are generated by defining a metric on rankings, after which the consensus ranking is a good "center point" in the induced metric space. Specifically, if we define the "distance" between two rankings as the "bubble-sort" distance between them, or the number of pairs on which they disagree, then the Kemeny optimal ranking is the ranking that minimizes the average distance to all the input rankings. A nice property of the Kemeny optimal ranking is that it is the unique ranking satisfying the extended Condorcet criterion while having other desirable properties as well.
All of this is explained in some detail in the pioneering paper by Dwork, Kumar, Naor and Sivakumar. When I was at VLDB I saw more examples of these methods being used to merge the results of multiple rankings. I should add that the problem of merging different rankings comes up in many different settings, so it is worth knowing the background in social choice theory.
Hmm. This reminds me of a book my friend has been pestering me to read:
ReplyDeleteBasic Geometry of Voting
by Donald G. Saari
Maybe I should read it now...
I haven't found Saari a good source on voting theory. He pushes his pet theory very hard, and gives short shrift to all other voting types.
ReplyDeletePosted by Anonymous